Is job growth impressive enough to stop worrying?
A look at unemployment and participation rates
The jobs picture:
unemployment and participation rates
The household report, the
source report for the unemployment rate calculation, registered 428,000 new
jobs in February. It saw 847,000 jobs created in January. That’s nearly 1.3
million jobs in two months. And we still have doubters… And 2.6million jobs have
been created according to the Household report in the last seven months. That’s an average of 371K per month. Private
nonfarm payrolls are up by just 1.3million over that seven month period for an
average of 191K per month. That’s a lot less than the household figure but not
a shabby showing.
Still the labor force
participation rate was around 0.66 (66%) before the recession/financial crisis and
it is only back to 0.639. So 2.1% - more - of the civilian population over the
age of 16 has headed to the side lines helping to suppress the unemployment
rate. Note that this is a proportion and in absolute terms the labor force is
rising; at a 1.6% annual rate over six months.
Population growth shows that
’women’ is the fastest growing class of labor followed by ‘teens’; ‘men’ is the
slowest expanding class.
The labor force shows its
fastest growth for women followed by men with teens the slowest
Employment is fastest growing
for men followed by women and teens. The
number unemployed is shrinking fastest for men second fastest for teens but it
is still rising for women. As a result
of these trends ‘men’ shows the slowest growth among the not in the labor force
groups followed by teens with women having the largest not-in-the-labor-force (NITLF)
growth rate.
Men are making the greatest
gains since they are being employed faster than other groups have the slowest
labor force growth, the fastest reduction in the ranks of unemployed and the
slowest growth of being NITLF. Men’s labor force growth is slow even though
their employment growth (part of the LF measure) is fast.
Cyclical Trends in Participation
The story of labor
force participation rates is being re-written and not just in this cycle. Since
1990 there has been a gradual increase in the tendency for labor force
participation rates to drop. In 1990 it was just the young and adult men along
with all teens. The teen plus adult men’s rate and the adult men’s rate have
steadily been shrinking. But the decline for adult men is accelerating in the
business cycle. So is the decline for teen and adult men. The teen and adult
women rate has been slowing and is now shrinking at an ever faster pace since
1973. Adult women continue to see their participation rate rise, but the pace
of that increase has slowed, and slowed sharply. In an all-inclusive
time-series format the adult women’s rate is down from its peak.
So there are several
kinds of forces that are in play. There are a number of category-specific
longer term trends that are in play. But it is also true that some of these
effects are intensifying over the most recent cycles. Women’s participation rates
once rising by 2.9 % points at the 32 month mark of recovery are up by just
0.10 pct points in this cycle. Historically, that was one of the important offsets
to the long term structural drop in men’s participation rates. The men’s drop
has had some vacillation but it has averaged a drop of 1% at the 32-month mark
of the expansion cycle. In this cycle the men’s rate has dropped by 1.8 %
points. The rate for teens has been dropping in a more accelerated fashion and
the drop of five percentage points at the 32-month mark is identical to the
drop at this point in the 2001 cycle.
In the 1990, 2001,
and 2008 cycles participation rates have been more prone to drop than in earlier
post war cycles. Interestingly 1960 is an exception.
People are
screaming about the high rate of unemployment and the Fed has swerved its policies
to try to reignite growth. Job growth is in gear again but participation rates
channel much broader trends. The Fed needs to be careful about being pushed to
achieve objectives that are beyond its grasp.
The metrics for
participation by educational attainment do not have a long history. But in this
recovery period the rate for those with less than a high school diploma is up
by 0.4% points from the recession end (yes, that’s UP). But for all other
educational; classes it is lower! For
participants with a high school diploma but not college the participation rate
is lower by 3.8% points. For those with some college but no degree the
participation rate is lower by 2.3% points. For those with a college degree
their participation rate is lower by 1.4% points.
The declines in
the unemployment rates have favored the less educated. For the least educated
group (no high school diploma) the drop in the unemployment rate since the
recession ended is 2.6% points; for high school grads it is -1.5% points for
those with some college it is -0.8% and for college grads the drop is 0.6% pts.
Now this also reflects the fact that the level of the unemployment rate is
highest for the least educated. But they still have had the greater
proportionate drop.
Caution Fed caution!!
The table above
breaks down unemployment rate progress by different categories of unemployment:
BY REASON. Job losers probably most come to mind when think of this category.
They make up 55% of it and included workers on temporary layoffs and on permanent
layoff (factories closed, out of business etc). Job leavers made up another 8%,
of the unemployed with re-entrants to the labor force accounting for one
quarter of the unemployed. New entrants are currently about 10% of the pool of
unemployed.
Compared to
historic norms the group ‘not temporarily unemployed’ is quite large. It makes
up 46% of the unemployed pool right now compared with a normal proportion of
37% and a previous high of 40% (1990 and 2001). The proportion unemployed
temporarily is 8.7% compare to an average of 12.1% and a previous low of 10%
(1970).
One implication
here is that a large bulk of the unemployed reflects people that are not simply
going back to their old jobs when the economy picks up.
The Fed may take
its dual mandate seriously. But these data suggest that a great big chuck of
the main unemployment problem is not simply cyclical. ‘Job leavers’ is at a low
proportion historically making up only 7.9% of total unemployment compared to
12% on average at this point in the recovery cycle . But ‘re-entrants’ and ‘new
entrants’ are at a near-normal proportion of total unemployment. Job leavers
may be few in numbers because, with such high unemployment, not many are
willing to leave jobs. So fewer wind up being unemployed. This low reading is
not a mark of success. The low quit rate reinforces this view.
There is another
way to assess unemployment by reason and that is to look at the contribution to
the rate of unemployment. Looked at through this lens the categories for
unemployment are all within one standard deviation of the previous mean for
unemployment by category at this point of the cycle except for ‘not temporary
job losers.’ Of course this means that the overall category that includes
this measure, Job Losers, also is distorted up. But the other component of job
losers, ‘temporary job losers’ is actually normal. What stands out it that the
unemployment rate is elevated by about 1.4 percentage points (it could be 6.9%)
except for the excessive strain on the category ‘not temporary job losers’. The
reading for this category is three standard deviations above the mean., a
reading that makes it impressively significant. And this category is a proper
target for fiscal policy not for monetary policy.
The Fed, as much
as it wants to boost growth, will have to be aware that this large crop of ‘permanent’
unemployed may be harder for the labor market to absorb. Having said that, the
table above show that the current level of permanently unemployed as a
percentage of the recession end peak is only 75% which is the second lowest
among all these cycles. Thus progress in reducing ‘permanent unemployment’ has
been quite good. But this has also been a very large pool of unemployed by
historic standards. Temporary unemployment is at 65% of its peak and that is
about normal at this point of the expansion.
Job leavers are
26% above their peak level but this class averages a higher number; at his stage
the expansion the average rise should be more like 11% not 26%.
Re-entrants are ‘doing
well’ by historic comparison as their ratio to their end recession level is low.
It is up 1% from its recession-end level and the norm would be to rise by 3% to
4%.
New entrants unemployed
are up 39% from their recession-end level while the norm is somewhere between
16% (average) and 25% (median). New
entrants are struggling to get back into the labor market.
On balance a number
of factors are in play in understanding participation rates and unemployment
rates. Many of them are out of the Fed’s control. Some are structural and
others are demographic. The danger is if the Fed pushes too hard to try and get
the unemployment rate down it could backfire. This past week we did see unit
labor costs elevate and they are up for two quarters running and are up to 3%
Yr/Yr. This may not be a sign that the Fed has reached its limits but job growth
is getting stronger has become more reliable with nearly all job gauges giving
off consistently firm readings. Still, the Fed is obsessed with its
multi-mandate. We can only hope that it will recognize, not just that it is
pushing on a string, but that it is pouring stuff into a punch bowl that is already
overflowing.
If might do a
better job of policy recognition error if is not as guilty as I am in mixing its
metaphors.
1 comment:
A low wage job economy.
Post a Comment